Reviewing Sebastian Mallaby’s biography of Alan Greenspan, Randall Kroszner writes,
The Fed has limited instruments at its disposal—primarily its control over short-term interest rates—and trying to use this tool for “bubble bursting” while still addressing the Fed’s traditional mandates for full employment and low and stable inflation could lead to conflicting prescriptions. Better, Mr. Greenspan believed, to be ready to clean up the debris if a bubble were to burst, as in 1987. Mr. Mallaby argues that the inflation-targeting framework, which focused central banks world-wide on the goal of low and stable inflation in response to their bad behavior in the 1970s when they eased credit in the short run to boost employment, provided an intellectual underpinning for Mr. Greenspan’s approach.
Indeed, it is useful to go back to what economists were thinking back when Olivier Blanchard was writing that “the state of macro is good.” The idea was that the GDP factory slumped when there were inflation “surprises,” in which prices increased more slowly than expected, leading to real wages that were too high. So if the Fed kept the inflation rate predictable (and it might as well shoot for a predictable rate that was low), then everything would be fine.
Some remarks:
1. Now, journalists want to paint Greenspan as a great free-marketeer, as if he spent his career fending off cries for more financial regulation. In fact, there was a consensus in the 1980s that inter-state banking had to arrive and that the Glass-Steagall separation of investment banking from commercial banking was being eroded by innovation. The deregulation that ratified these changes would have happened under any conceivable Fed chairman at that time. Moreover, the deregulation was accompanied by what banking officials were convinced at the time were stronger and more effective regulations regarding safety and soundness. They were particularly proud of risk-based capital regulations, and it was the market-oriented economists of the Shadow Regulatory Committee who warned that those were not adequate to prevent a crisis.
2. The “(dis-)inflation surprise” theory of economic slumps is now gone. The closest thing remaining is Scott Sumner’s slower-nominal-GDP theory of slumps. That one works for the post-financial-crisis recession because real GDP went way down, which (a) meant that nominal GDP growth was slower than previously and (b) tautologically, there was a slump. I am troubled by the tautology aspect.
3. However, the Keynesians who dominate the current macro conversation have different theories. Some like to tell a story about consumer debt. Many like to tell a story about a liquidity trap.
4. Speaking for macroeconomists in general Blanchard is now open to many different ideas. However, the one idea that they will not consider changing is the GDP factory. Thus, the idea that patterns of sustainable specialization and trade matter is not on the radar screen.