Changes in the corporate landscape

Kathleen M. Kahle and René M. Stulz write (link now fixed),

US public firms are very different now compared to 1975 or 1995: fewer, larger, older, less-profitable, with more intangible capital, less investment, and other changes. The US firms that remain public are mostly survivors. Few firms want to join their club. A small number of firms account for most of the market capitalization, most of the earnings, most of the cash, and most of the payouts of public firms. At the industry level, revenues are more concentrated, so fewer public firms are competing for customers. A large fraction of firms do not earn profits every year and that fraction is especially large in recent years, which helps to explain the high level of delists. Accounting standards do not reflect the importance of intangible assets for listed firms, which may make it harder for executives to invest for the long run.

The authors discuss various explanations for this, but my inclination is to tell the story as follows:

Think of any investment project as going through two phases. First, there is the start-up phase, which may or may not produce profitable results. Then, for successful projects, there is the cashing-in phase, where the profitable enterprise gets sold to a wider set of investors.

Forty years ago, a lot of investment projects were started within large public firms. With the firm already public, there was no need for an additional cash-in phase. The stock already was widely held. Meanwhile, if a not-yet-public firm launched a successful enterprise, the best deal it could get in the cash-in phase was often to go public.

Today, large public firms are doing less of the first-phase risky investment. Instead, they are letting private firms take the risks and then handling the successful start-ups’ cash-in phase for them by buying them.

So that’s a story. A leading example of that model would be pharma. A lot of the speculative research gets done at small start-ups. Once a start-up is successful, its best option is to be acquired by big pharma. The legacy firms have a comparative advantage in handling the second phase. The start-ups have a comparative advantage in the first phase.

Scarcity of financial intermediation?

Ricardo J. Caballero, Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas write,

For the last few decades, with minor cyclical interruptions, the supply of safe assets has not kept up with global demand. The reason is straightforward: the collective growth rate of the advanced economies that produce safe assets has been lower than the world’s growth rate, which has been driven disproportionately by the high growth rate of high-saving emerging economies such as China. If demand for safe assets is proportional to global output, this shortage of safe assets is here to stay.

The signature of this growing shortage is a steady increase in the price of safe assets, necessary to restore equilibrium in this market. Equivalently, global safe interest rates must decline, as has been the case since the 1980s. Simultaneously, we observed a surge in cross-border purchases of safe assets by safe asset demanders—many of them located in emerging economies—from safe asset producers, mostly the United States.

I get their point, but I do not like the idea of talking about the quantity of safe assets as the problem. Remember my view of finance: people want to issue risky, long-term liabilities and hold riskless, short-term assets. Financial intermediaries accommodate this by doing the opposite. Hence these thoughts:

1. What my framework suggests is that if there are too few riskless, short-term assets, then there must also be too few risky, long-term liabilities. That is, there is a general shortage of financial intermediation.

2. There does not appear to be a general shortage of financial intermediation. Relative to the economy, the financial sector has been growing, not shrinking.

3. In the “safe assets” framework, government helps to solve the problem of safe-asset scarcity by printing more money and issuing more short-term debt. In my framework, more government liabilities are not helpful. Government’s short-term, riskless liabilities are not backed by long-term risky assets.* So government is not increasing the amount of financial intermediation. Government instead is crowding out financial intermediation.

*You could say that the government’s risky, long-term assets are future tax revenues. But it is not the case that governments are raising money in order to invest in projects that will lead to increased future tax revenues. They are mostly making transfer
payments.

4. In fact, a lot of financial activity is associated with funding the government. So it could be that what I think of financial intermediation has declined even though financial activity has increased.

5. In other words, perhaps the financial sector is growing but not increasing its holding of risky, long-term assets. If so, this could be due to many things, but I think that the political assault on banks (regulations, “settlements” with prosecutors) comes to the top of my mind. Politicians bash the financial sector as being unproductive even as they increase the intensity of their utilization of the financial sector to channel money toward political ends.

6. The interest rate on safe assets is not a good measure of where interest rates are relative to some Wicksellian natural rate. In other words, don’t worry about the interest rate on safe assets being too low. Worry about the interest rate on a typical risky, long-term asset being too high relative to its natural rate. But changes in any given market interest rate on long-term, risky assets get confounded with changes in expected inflation and in risk perception.

Amazon arithmetic in a bubble, continued

A commenter writes,

AWS (the Amazon “cloud”), is wildly profitable (20%+ margins), and while only 10% of their revenue currently, is growing much (over 2x) faster than the rest of the business.

He offers these figures for the second quarter:

Amazon Web Services $4.1 billion revenue, $0.9 billion profit, revenue growth rate of 50 percent per year.

Amazon excluding AWS $33.5 billion revenue, $1.5 billion loss, revenue growth rate of 22 percent per year.

So let me play with these numbers a bit, to try to get to $12.5 billion in profit, which I think is needed to justify the current stock valuation. We have four numbers to play with: AWS revenue, AWS margin, ex-AWS revenue, and ex-AWS margin.

1. Start with a combination of AWS margin of 20 percent, ex-AWS margin of 0. Then we need AWS revenue to be at $62.5 billion, compared to $4.1 currently. That might not happen for . . .ever.

2. Start with a combination of AWS margin of 20 percent and ex-AWS margin of 4 percent. At current revenues, that gives them $.9 billion and $1.34 billion, respectively, for $2.24 billion. That means that they have to grow revenue in each sector by a factor of 5 to get to $12.5 billion in profit. Even if AWS maintains a 50 percent growth rate, it would take 4 years to go up by a factor of 5. And it would take ex-AWS a lot longer. All while supposedly goosing their profit margins in retail to 4 percent.

Another commenter notes that Dean Baker thinks the way I do about Amazon.

Other commenters have said that profits are understated, because Amazon has plenty of “free cash flow” that it is currently spending to try to enhance its capabilities. OK, but Amazon’s revenues are not understated. They had $38 billion in quarterly revenue. How much of that could possibly be profit, under the most generous accounting?

I’ve got $100 that says the market cap of Amazon is lower on July 31, 2020 than it is today.

Arithmetic in a bubble, once again

Mark J. Perry writes,

Amazon and Facebook were in the news this week for “joining an exclusive club open to only the richest companies in the world: both crossed the half-a-trillion mark.” Those two companies join Apple ($785 billion as of today), Alphabet/Google ($652 billion), and Microsoft ($564 billion) in the exclusive club of companies whose market capitalization tops $500 billion. To put the size of that market cap into perspective, consider that the entire Mexican stock exchange has a current market valuation of $438 billion, Thailand’s publicly traded stocks are worth $468 billion and the Russian stock exchange has a market cap of $554 billion! Together, the five US companies in the “$500 billion” club have a combined value of nearly $3 trillion… To put that into perspective, just those five US companies, as a separate country or stock exchange, would be the eight largest stock market in the world (see table above), and 40% larger than No. 9 Canada’s entire stock market and almost 50% (and $1 trillion) larger than the German stock exchange!

Some arithmetic:

Amazon just reported quarterly earnings of $200 million. At that rate, it would take 2500 quarters to earn $500 billion. That is 625. Years.

Call me impatient, but I do not care to wait 625 years to earn back my investment. I would rather see the money paid back a bit sooner. Like maybe 10 years.

If you want a $500 billion investment paid back in 10 years, then you need quarterly earnings of $12.5 billion. What does Amazon have to do to achieve that?

Their earnings are their sales times their profit margin. Investopedia writes,

Each year, the S&P 500 releases industry specific returns on equity and net margins, and each year the retail industry is among the least profitable. This is especially true for web-only retailers, which often see net margins as low as 2.50 to 3.50%.

So if we assume that Amazon is capable of achieving a 4 percent profit margin, we are being generous. At that profit margin, to get $12.5 billion in quarterly earnings, you would need $312.5 billion in sales. Actual sales last quarter were $38 billion.

Unless I have made some errors (check to see that I haven’t messed up by a factor of 10 somewhere), this arithmetic says that Amazon needs to be 8 times as big as it is, with a generous profit margin, in order to make me want to own the stock.

In July of 1999, I wrote Arithmetic in a Bubble. My first blog was an extended exploration of the topic. Maybe it is time for that blog to make a comeback.

How to Handle the payments system

The commenter suggests,

simply nationalize the “deposits taking and transaction processing” function of the banking industry? Everyone gets a zero-service-fee fully electronic (no paper checks) account at the Federal Reserve

Picture this as a retail version of the Fed Funds market. To simplify, I would not have any interest on Fed Funds.

Let’s say that I keep most of my liquid assets with a money market fund. But when I want to add to my Fed Funds, I sell money market fund shares and the money market fund transfers Fed Funds out of its account and into my account. When I want to buy things, I send money from my Fed Funds account to the Fed Funds account of the seller. Maybe I use a debit card to execute the transaction. Maybe I use my phone.

The idea is that this insulates the payment processing system from the solvency of financial institutions. These Fed Funds accounts would not be vulnerable to runs.

There would still be financial institutions doing bank-like things, including holding long-term risky assets and issuing short-term riskless (supposedly) liabilities. They could still get in trouble. And the government probably would still want to regulate them, in order to steer credit toward its preferred uses, including financing its own debt.

But it is an interesting thought-experiment.

The Grumpy Bank Holding Company Proposal

John Cochrane writes,

For $100 of assets, and $100 of bank equity, let, say, $10 of that equity be traded — enough to establish a liquid market. Then, let $90 of that equity is held by a downstream entity or entities— a fund, special purpose vehicle, holding company or other money bucket. I’ll call it a holding company, and return to legal structures below. The holding company, in turn, issues $10 of holding company equity and $80 of debt.

The good news is that the bank can never fail, and if the holding company becomes insolvent, Cochrane suggests that it could quickly force debt holders to accept a new mix of (less) debt and some equity.

The bad news is that the debt of the bank holding company, which is the closest thing to bank money in his world, will not trade at par. It will trade at a discount, which will be small if the bank seems to be doing well and large if the bank seems to be doing poorly. For transaction purposes, that sort of money is noisy, so it will not really work. If it would work, then nobody would be bothered by a money market fund that can “break the buck.” In order to avoid breaking the buck, money market funds have to stick to non-risky assets.

I think that in order to work as money, financial liabilities have to trade at par. If a firm has risky assets and most of its liabilities trade at par, then I think it has to be subject to runs (assuming no deposit insurance). I don’t see any way around that.

Bank Lending and Non-bank Lending

Daniel Nevins, in Economics for Independent Thinkers, a book I mentioned the other day, thinks of non-bank lending as coming from savings and bank lending as created by fiat. I do not think in those terms.

Think of an economy that includes fruit tree growers, households, and banks. The fruit trees represent risky, long-term investments.

The fruit tree growers finance their investment with a combination of debt and fruit-tree equity. Households may purchase some of the fruit tree debt directly. This would be called non-bank lending. Banks purchase the rest of the fruit-tree debt and fund it with a combination of bank equity and liquid deposits. The fruit tree debt that the banks fund is owned indirectly by households.

In the aggregate, households hold everything. Not every household is identical, but in the aggregate they hold the fruit tree equity, the direct fruit tree debt, and the indirect fruit tree debt that comes to the household in the form of bank equity and liquid deposits.

Now, fruit tree growers are households, just like anyone else. So you can think of an increase in bank lending as a bank creating a deposit at the household of a fruit tree grower in exchange for more debt issued by that fruit tree grower. That may be the way that Nevins wants to think of it,, and he thinks that this makes it much different from non-bank lending, because the bank can create a deposit seemingly out of thin air. He would say that it does so without prior saving, although he adheres to the identity between current saving and current investment.

In contrast, I think of bank lending and non-bank lending as doing the same thing, namely funding the debt issued by fruit tree growers. The only difference is that with non-bank lending, households have a direct ownership of the debt, while with bank lending their ownership is indirect.

Households may have a limited appetite for direct holding of fruit tree debt. And they may have a less limited appetite for holding that debt indirectly. In that case, if fruit tree growers and bank managers become more risk tolerant, you may get an expansion of fruit tree investment along with an increase in bank lending. Conversely, if fruit tree growers and bank managers become more risk averse, you may get a contraction.

The bottom line is that I think that bank credit matters, just as Nevins does. But I am not comfortable with his semantics.

Why pick on big banks?

A reader writes,

I would describe the posture of big banks (and other well-heeled financial institutions) as “pleading for mercy,” more than “buying friends and influence.” Banks are giant piles of treasure and if in the olden times they would send hordes, spells and dragons, now they send the DOJ, regulators (state, fed and quasi-public, like FINRA) and the plaintiffs’ bar.

Big banks are subject to shakedowns by grandstanding government officials. But I think that in exchange for paying this “tax,” big banks get enough benefits from government that they are better off big.

I do not believe that there are economies of scale in banking at such high levels. We do not see banks get large organically. They get large through mergers. The result is to create institutions with very high levels of operational risk, because senior management cannot possibly keep track of what the various units are doing. But if one of the units messes up, the taxpayers are there to provide a bailout.

A commenter writes,

1) In reality, it was the medium size banks or investment banks that were the worst offenders. not the largest one. In the case of the largest ones, only Citi really was that borderline survived if you assume BofA was sort shotgun to take Meryll Lynch.
2) Haven’t most long time businesses consolidated a lot the last 30 years. Grocery stores or airlines. The economy has naturally moved this direction with most long time businesses.
3) Historically the US has been the developed world oddball with a heavy local banking presence.
4) In terms of the S&L crisis there was bailouts and lots of failure of small institutions. In fact the government probably wrote a bigger check on that crisis than the 2008 Housing Crisis despite being significantly smaller.

Regarding point (4), the bailout cost the taxpayers $150 billion. Even adjusting for inflation, the bill for the financial crisis was quite a bit higher. Also, most of the cost of the S&L crisis could have been avoided had the regulators not relied on “extend and pretend.” The S&L business model was destroyed by inflation in the 1970s, but most of the clean-up did not take place until a decade later, by which time the losses had multiplied.

Regarding point (3), this is very much a plus for the United States in my opinion. We have the best developed stock markets and venture capital market in the world in part because until the 1980s our banking system was unusually fragmented. There is a decent argument (made most strongly by Calomiris and Haber) that our banking system was too fragmented historically, but by now I believe that our banking system is too concentrated.

Regarding point (2), there are industries where firms grew to dominate because of superior execution and/or economies of scale. That is definitely not how the top banks in the U.S. became large. They got big through mergers. And through all sorts of regulatory barriers to competition.

Moreover, in other industries there has been new entry. The competition in groceries in recent decades has been very intense. Airline competition has been more uneven, but still there has been much more entry than in banking, even though the fixed cost of getting an airline operating would appear to be much higher than the fixed cost of opening a bank.

Regarding point (1), I do not claim that big banks are inherently riskier or more poorly run than smaller institutions. My main problems with big banks are:

1. Their CEOs have immediate access to key politicians.

2. Money managers who lend to banks have to multiply the probability that the bank is/becomes insolvent times the probability that it will not be bailed out. For small banks, the second probability is not high, because the FDIC tries to resolve these banks with mergers, and that leads to excess willingness to lend to those banks. But for small banks, the second probability is exactly zero, and that distorts behavior even more.

3. In a crisis, the big banks are certain to receive bailouts. The CEO of a big bank can expect huge rewards for success, or even for mediocrity, with no accountability at all for failure. How could the rest of us not feel angry about that situation?

Perhaps we need peer regulation in finance

Guy Rolnik writes,

After acknowledging that the OCC knew of the issues within Wells Fargo as far back as 2010, it stated that “The OCC did not take timely and effective supervisory actions after the bank and the OCC identified significant issues with complaint management and sales practices.” The report also said that the team in charge of Wells Fargo “focused too heavily on bank processes versus what those processes were actually reporting” and “reached conclusions without testing or determining the root causes of complaints despite the existence of red flags.”

Pointer from Mark Thoma. Read the whole essay, which concludes,

Executives knew, board members knew (or should have known), and regulators knew almost all along, yet failed to do anything about it.

To me, this hints at the problems with the way that we currently try to deal with misbehavior on the part of financial firms. Top executives can be unreliable. Boards of directors are often unwilling or unable to delve deeply into operational issues. Regulators are just going through the motions.

There is one constituency that often really cares about financial firms that misbehave: their peers. When you lose customers to a firm that is using shady products and sales practices, you get angry. Unfortunately, the most profitable response is often to copy what the bad guys are doing.

I suggest creating a Financial Ethical Standards Board (FESB), which is analogous to FASB. FESB would provide a forum for discussing and offering guidance on ethics in the financial industry. If you see a competitor doing something unethical, you can take your complaint to FESB. FESB would have the ability to name and shame the wrongdoers, and it would have the ability to focus the attention of regulators.

I believe that a down side of FESB, or peer regulation in general, is that firms would try to use it to resist innovation that they find threatening but which in fact is not unethical. But I think that we can live with this potential down side in exchange for better regulation of the financial industry.

The way I see it, ordinary regulation simply gives clarity to banks about what they can get away with. As the banks adapt, ordinary regulation becomes ineffective, or even counterproductive. Peer regulation would be more adaptive. I believe it would be better, although nothing is perfect.

Should Wal-Mart be allowed into banking?

Ronald J. Mann wrote,

Wal-Mart’s application to form a bank ignited controversy among disparate groups, ranging from union backers to realtor’s groups to charitable organizations. The dominant voice, though, was that of independent bankers complaining that the big-box retailer would drive them out of business. Wal-Mart denied any interest in competing with local banks by opening branches, claiming that it was interested only in payments processing. Distrusting Wal-Mart, the independent bankers urged the FDIC to deny Wal-Mart’s request and lobbied state and federal lawmakers to block Wal-Mart’s plans through legislation. Ultimately, WalMart withdrew its application, concluding that it stood little chance of overcoming the opposition.

I was reminded of this by Lawrence J. White, who had written a piece in favor of allowing Wal-Mart into banking.

We are always told that we need regulation to protect consumers and make the financial system safer. That is the theory. The practice is that regulation very often gets used to limit competition.

This is an example of what I mean when I say that in any dispute between libertarians and statists, the libertarians are usually right.