[Note: askblog had an existence prior to the virus crisis. I still schedule occasional posts like this one.]
A commenter asks,
Could you write an explanation of the financial / economic logic behind stock buybacks, vs. lowering debt and/or paying out dividends?
My cynical view is that 90 percent of financial strategy is either tax minimization, regulatory arbitrage (coming up with instruments to comply with the letter of regulations while violating their spirit), or accounting charades (complying with the letter of accounting rules while disguising reality).
In the case of stock buybacks, I lean toward tax minimization. I suspect that stock buybacks are the most tax-efficient use of surplus cash.
If you reduce debt, the corporation will pay more in taxes, because the interest payments on the debt were tax deductible. Incidentally, this is a pet peeve of economists, because it provides an incentive for high leverage. I think that the best thing to do is get rid of the corporate income tax, which is best describe as a swiss cheese that is mostly holes. But the holes all distort behavior in some way.
If the corporation pays me a dividend, that is ordinary income to me for tax purposes. If the corporation instead buys back stock, the income I get comes from a higher share price, which I can hold until it is taxable as a long-term capital gain.
As Warren Buffett once wrote:
“There is only one combination of facts that makes it advisable for a company to repurchase its shares: First, the company has available funds — cash plus sensible borrowing capacity — beyond the near-term needs of the business and, second, finds its stock selling in the market below its intrinsic value, conservatively-calculated. To this we add a caveat: Shareholders should have been supplied all the information they need for estimating that value. Otherwise, insiders could take advantage of their uninformed partners and buy out their interests at a fraction of true worth.”
1999 Letter to Berkshire Hathaway shareholders
http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/letters/1999htm.html
The rest of his discussion of repurchases is worth reading.
“If the corporation pays me a dividend, that is ordinary income to me for tax purposes. If the corporation instead buys back stock, the income I get comes from a higher share price, which I can hold until it is taxable as a long-term capital gain.”
This is the correct answer – the most tax efficient way to return excess funds to shareholders. Not that complicated.
One other good reason: to offset the dilution caused by employees exercising stock options or vesting in RSUs (or similar units).
This is incorrect: dividend income from most corporations also qualifies for long-term capital gains rates.
The big difference between the stock buybacks and dividends is that with the former, you have the ability to offset your original cost investment (your tax basis) against the repurchase price of the stock. So you only pay long-term gain on the appreciation.
“This is incorrect: dividend income from most corporations also qualifies for long-term capital gains rates.”
Are you forgetting the time value of money here? Increase in stock price due to a share repurchase is fully deferred from taxation until the underlying shares are sold. Dividends are taxed upon receipt…no option to defer that tax.
No. That’s not a good reason. If the stock is overvalued at the time, for example, it fails the check described by Warren Buffett, then to do the buy back at that time will be adverse for the remaining majority of stockholders.
Most owners of most shares are rich – whose buying and selling always include tax considerations.
Dividends go to all owners. Buyback cash this year only goes to those who sell, often as part of a tax minimization strategy on their whole portfolio and all of their transactions. Those who don’t sell don’t see cash, but do have an deferred taxed increase in their asset wealth. The shareowners have much more influence in a buyback where they can sell all, none, or some maximally advantageous amount, as compared to just getting dividend cash.
For companies with declining top line revenue, like IBM, buybacks keep the share prices high and also reduce the outstanding shares. It would seem to also increase the volume of transactions in the market, which should increase the liquidity.
I’m in the tax business myself. The above was true until 1986, which is why Microsoft was known during that period as having never paid a dividend, and always bought back its shares instead. (The 1986 Reagan tax bill did away with separate tax rates for capital gains. That policy only lasted 2-3 years before Congress recreated them, but Microsoft never resumed its policy of buybacks even afterward. I don’t know why not.)
Under current tax law, though, most corporate dividends are “qualified” and thus are taxed at capital gains rates. So I don’t think a buyback policy today would benefit most companies or their owners.
Stock buybacks are also a good way for management to pay themselves out of the corporate budget, assuming they have stock or options for stock.
As a strategy for good times, that’s plausible. But as with anything involving debt and leverage, it does seem a bit risky and something that could backfire badly in bad times.
If a company got most of its money from stock sales, then when profits collapse, it may have to take some losses, but it doesn’t become worthless, or face a certain risk of not being able to make interest payments, and it has a lot of extra room to get some short term credit to make other payments and get it through a temporary bad time.
If a company got a ton of its money from debts, then when things go bad, it risks default and has little room for maneuver. The shareholders are now at risk of getting wiped out and the creditors take their haircuts and own the company.
But that would mean the executives and whoever else is paid in stock all got wiped out too in such an event. Is there some common attempt to insure themselves against such an outcome?
Note: most bond covenants specifically restrict the amount and timing of share repurchases (and dividends) based on strict covenant formula that are calculated monthly. It’s not like the corporate officers have carte blanche to buyback stock at the their heart’s content.
Don’t forget compensation-maximization. If option strike prices don’t adjust for dividends paid you are better off returning capital via buybacks.
This has always been my theory.
Matt Levine gave his explanation of buybacks in his Money Stuff column yesterday:
It’s worth noting that long-term capital gains are taxed at (IIRC) 15%, and ordinary income is taxed at a variable but generally much higher rate.
This is justified by the “need” to attract investment. The rich investors would invest less without this reduced capital gains rate.
In a low-interest world, with plenty of capital, this argument is now very, very weak. Where else are the rich investors going to invest? The lower rate is part of how gov’t makes it easier for the rich to get richer faster than the median folk.
I support tax changes to make the median wage earner get richer faster than the top 10% or top 1%. So I’d favor equal income treatment to capital gains (from capital) as from wage income (labor).
One serious problem with buybacks instead of dividends is that investors don’t always have a choice in when and how much of their stock they sell.
I speak from painful experience. In an ordinary year, I’m near the top of the bracket that pays 0% on dividends and capital gains. In 2018, however, Rockwell Collins, which I’d owned for forty-some years, was acquired by United Technologies, and I had to pay capital-gains tax on essentially the full value of my Rockwell. This kicked me into a much higher income-tax bracket, and subjected me to the 3.8% Obamacare surtax to boot.
If I’m getting a regular stream of dividends, I can plan around it, knowing that the income and the taxes I pay on it won’t vary drastically from year to year. That’s not the case with buyback-induced increases in stock value, which don’t increase my income gradually with time and which subject me to occasional years in which I have to write an enormous check on April 15.
I think the incentive structure faced by managements matters. Most of them hold stock options. Buybacks benefit option holders more than dividends do.
I think Matt Levine is spot on: buybacks are more tax efficient not because they might or might not incur a lower tax rate, but because they distribute the tax liability away from the current holders of the stock and onto those shareholders who prefer to exit. If you’re a committed long-term holder, they shield you from taxes while you own the stock. Per Don Castigo’s point that dividends help you manage your tax brackets and future tax liabilities, you can still do that by selling a small portion of your shares each year. (I think one of the main tasks of financial education should be to point out this option).
This argument does not negate the very good point that in a company that rewards its managers in stock options that are not adjusted for dividends, the managers would be biased to prefer that the company steer distributions towards buybacks. (The solution to this incentive problem seems simple: just adjust the option strike prices for dividends).
From the standpoint of fundamental company value (which is all that shareholders should ultimately care about), buybacks, in practice, are only preferable if the management has an astute sense of the real value of the company; and only conducts them when its market value has dipped far below the real value. So buybacks are preferable when you trust the management to be disciplined; and dividends are preferable when you don’t. It’s a subjective choice.
“The corporate income tax, which is best described as a swiss cheese that is mostly holes.”
That is a keeper. Is it a Klingism? My guess would be that it’s much older.
While we are at it, it would be nice to have a larger glossary. It must have been done already. It provides a good primer for Cultural Literacy. For example…
Director’s Law
Capture Theory
Harberger’s Triangle
etc, &c
I just googled all three and got reasonable explanations very quickly.
Sorry–long answer follows…
My recollection was that Deirdre McCloskey presented it as “Harberger’s Postulate: If you multiply a very large number of fractions together you get a very small number.”
It’s funnier if you do it with a stand-up comedian’s delivery. You need to build suspense about the difficulty of measuring welfare losses from monopoly. You soften up the audience by going on for a few minutes about the buckets of ink spilled on this for decades. And of course there is the the great effort put into seeing just big a problem this is.
Then you say “Harberger’s Postulate”: …. (wait for it…)
“When you multiply a lot of fractions together you get a very small number.”
That’s how I learned it. Maybe you had to be there.
That one wasn’t quite so self-evident, because all I got was an article that mentioned three postulates. It’s in J-STOR which for me is paywalled. The abstract didn’t seem nearly so funny as the way I heard the story told, either.
Wondering out loud. As a shareholder, is it a higher risk for the corporation to buy back instead of give a dividend? The scenario I paint is that there is always a risk of the company stock doing a permanent crater or even being wiped out. If the corporation had given dividends over a 10 year period vs buybacks, isn’t your risk adjusted position better?