I have finished my first path through the Weintraub volume. Here are my thoughts now:
1. There truly was a dramatic break between pre-war and postwar economics. Before the second World War, you could still see economics as a branch of social and political philosophy. And as philosophers, economists were worried about what they could and could not know. After the war, the discipline became dominated by modeling. Some of that was a long-term trend, and some of it came from the fact that modeling was applied to some aspects of the war effort itself.
2. Samuelson and Solow were part of a transitional generation. They were exponents of the newer modeling culture, but they still had plenty of doubts about the assumptions embedded in models.
3. The next generation of MIT economists, I would argue, was never trained to question assumptions. Once a particular equation had become customary, because a lot of papers used that equation, you just treated the equation as true. Think of the Cobb-Douglas production function, or the expectations-augmented Phillips Curve.
4. Samuelson’s self-image was that of an ideologically neutral technocrat. In the Weintraub volume, Harro Maas writes,
Technicality implied impartiality and detachment. Samuelson thus exemplifies for economics the general move of science in the postwar era to define itself as technical, a move that fit well with the teaching and research profile that MIT developed in the postwar era.
And later,
Samuelson did not consider it his task to be partisan for one particular line of economic policy, or to compromise between opposite policy positions, but to step back, or better “step aside,” and offer an analytical perspective from which to choose.
5. Of course, I would view Samuelson’s very framework as ideologically loaded. Samuelson took a “seeing like a state” approach to economics. Whether it was a social welfare function, a Keynesian multiplier, the doctrine of revealed preference, the Phillips Curve, or the production function, he focused on tools for helping policy makers control an economy. With such tools, the policy maker could know enough to direct economic activity. Samuelson was not troubled by Hayekian concerns about local knowledge.