David Henderson’s pessimistic bet

He writes,

I bet that by the end of the calendar year, the number of deaths that can clearly be attributed to the disease will be greater than 100,000.

Note that he hopes he loses his bet, as do we all.

Think of 100,000 as 10 million cases times a 1 percent death rate.

Why might we get more than 10 million cases? First, it is possible that the number of cases that have not been officially detected is 100x the number of official cases. Because some infected people do not have symptoms, some who have symptoms are not going to get tested, and some who want to be tested have been, until recently, turned away.

Even if the true number of cases in the U.S. is only 10,000 today, if that were to double ten times we would be at 10 million. If the doubling time were a week, it would take only ten weeks to be over 10 million. And as of now the doubling rate is faster than that in many European countries and in the U.S.

But given the sharp reduction in travel and large gatherings that has taken place, I expect that the doubling rate will slow down. Suppose that, after these changes have been in place for a few weeks, we find that it is taking a month or more to double the number of cases. That would make it less likely that we hit the 10 million total by the end of the year. (Although, again, it is hard to know where we are starting from.)

We might also find that we have a lower death rate. Compared with other countries, we have less smoking and more capacity in our health care system. And the steps that we take to protect at-risk populations from the virus may prove effective.

This might be a time to update the status of two hypothetical bets of mine. First, I hypothetically bet that no centrist candidate would arrive at the Democratic convention with more than 40 percent of the delegates. That now looks like a bad bet.

More recently, I hypothetically bet that the number of Covid-19 cases in the U.S. would be more than 12,000 by the end of this week. As of Tuesday evening, the total was over 6000, and it appeared to be doubling every two or three days. Unfortunately, it looks like I will turn out to be correct on that one.

Macroeconomics of the crisis, 6

Tyler Cowen has a short paper on the topic.

The key point is that in the short run we want economic activity to fall in ways that will curb the spread of the virus. In the long run, we want economic activity to come back.

In my view, the primary channel by which a short-term reduction in economic activity leads to a long-term decline is the financial channel. I have an essay on that, which I will post below the fold. Continue reading

Macroeconomics of the virus crisis, 5

A reader writes,

I’m seeing millions of people, primarily at the middle to lower end of the economic spectrum, who will be financially ruined by the response.

While remaining humane and just, is there a more cost effective approach to the problem, particularly since it seems concentrated in a rather narrow subset of the population (those with compromised immune systems and the 60+ cohort)? E.g. instead of isolating the entire population, why not just isolate those most at risk and compensate them accordingly? How do we weigh the ethical concerns of one group as against another? Why do such questions seem so out of bounds and antisocial?

1. I think that even the “low-risk” population, if they move about freely, are likely to overwhelm the health care system. I doubt that encouraging them to go about their business is the first-best strategy. But it might work out better than other approaches.

2. What we are doing now, which is lockdown-lite, is also not the first-best strategy. It may exacerbate economic pain while failing to do enough to stop the virus. It may be an instance of my two-weeks-behind hypothesis. Still, I think we ought to support the lockdown-lite approach–as you know, my wife and I adopted self-quarantining last Thursday. We ought to give it a chance.

3. I suspect that the first-best strategy is a total, nationwide lockdown for two weeks, enforced militarily. The intent would be to deprive the virus of hosts. Even then, in order to contain subsequent outbreaks, we would have to continue to encourage social distancing, require people to keep track of contacts, and do a lot of random testing of asymptomatic people.

Think of this as comparable to the Arab oil embargo. Probably the harder the adjustment we make sooner, the better it will be. The macroeconomic policies of that era made things worse, and I expect the same to happen today.

I cringe at all the talk of monetary and fiscal “stimulus.” What this means is that governments will use the crisis to enlarge their share of the economy, which will hurt the adjustment process, not help it. It will also “solve” the problem of debt collapse by piling on more debt.

Herd immunity and exposure policy

Robin Hanson wrote,

it isn’t crazy to consider cutting pandemic deaths via more infection inequality, including via deliberate exposure.

Pointer from Bryan Caplan.

Consider the following strategy:

1. Separate the population into low-risk and high-risk groups, based on their conditional probability of death if they get the virus. For example, young people with healthy immune systems vs. older people and/or those with compromised immune systems. Separate them not only conceptually, but physically–don’t let anyone from one group get near someone from the other group.

2. Then, allow the low-risk group to become infected, while keeping them away from the high-risk group.

3. Once the low-risk group have recovered, let the two groups mix.

Two reasons to hesitate about doing this. One is that it is not certain that people who have had the virus are immune. There are anecdotes about people re-acquiring the disease. Perhaps there are multiple strains, rather than “the” virus.

A second reason to hesitate is the high rate of death among health care providers, many of whom are young with healthy immune systems. This suggests that there are some other factors that affect risk, and you want to know more about those other factors before you try this approach.

My own “out of the box” suggestion is a program to test a random sample of people who are asymptomatic. That would give us a better idea of the dynamics of virus spreading.

I wish I could bet Roger Kimball

He writes,

Here’s what I think you’ll find if you track things for the next week. The number of cases will go up by 500-1000 cases per day for the next couple of days. Then the increase will start to decline. The number of deaths will also go up, but modestly. I suspect that by the end of this coming week the total number of cases will be around 6000, the total number of deaths 100-150.

I bet that the number of cases by the end of this coming week will be more than double his estimate.

Consider the following math problem:

You observe a petri dish for 24 hours. The amount of bacteria is doubling every hour. At the start, there is only a microscopic amount of bacteria. Right at the end of 24 hours, the petri dish is filled with bacteria. When do you suppose that the petri dish was half filled with bacteria?

Many of my readers will arrive at the correct answer after a few seconds. I would bet that Roger Kimball would not be able to answer the question correctly within five minutes. And if you cannot do that, you should keep your views on the virus crisis to yourself.

In his own way, Nassim Taleb tries to explain why it is unethical not to pay attention to the exponential.

In a more easily-understood way, these physicians make the point.

If our health care system fails, then we will all suffer. If the hospital is choked with COVID-19 patients, people with appendicitis, heart attacks, broken ankles, and so on will not be able to be treated. This is the picture of systemic risk. Everyone is at risk if there is a systemic failure of our health care system, not just those with COVID-19.

The challenge is this: By following the appropriate recommended social isolation measures, you will be saving lives of not just those at increased risk who are infected, but also those who need other critical health care services, including potentially yourself. You will be saving the lives of people you will never meet.

Who should follow our suggested social isolation measures? EVERYONE. If you do not need to go out for a mission-critical purpose, do not. Again, you WILL be saving the lives of at-risk members of your own family, as well as people you will never have the pleasure of meeting.

This reinforces to my thought process.

Heather MacDonald’s reasoning is not sound

Heather MacDonald writes,

Even assuming that coronavirus deaths in the United States increase by a factor of one thousand over the year, the resulting deaths would only outnumber annual traffic deaths by 2,200.

It is unsound to compare a relatively stable number (traffic deaths) to an exponential (the coronavirus). I hope that she will re-think and retract.

She writes as if increasing by a factor of 1000 is some sort of ridiculous upper bound. In fact, if we were to go ahead with business as usual and not do self-quarantining and social distancing, we would have to be darn lucky to have deaths increase only by a factor of 1000.

Lately, the number of cases in the U.S. and many European countries seems to be doubling every three days. If that pace continues, then in thirty days the number of cases will already be one thousand times what we have today. And in another two weeks, it would be 32,000 times the number of cases today.

Given this rate of spreading, one can expect that the number of deaths would double more rapidly than the number of cases. That is because the health care system would be overwhelmed. There would be too many critically ill patients to be able to treat them all.

As of Friday afternoon, there were about 2000 cases in the U.S. If 1000x were the upper bound for the spread of the virus, then we would see 2 million cases. If I thought that Americans could go about our normal business and have no more than 2 million cases, I would advocate going about our normal business. But instead, even with the actions that we have taken to date (note that these are less drastic than actions taken in several other countries), I think that holding the number of cases to 2 million would be optimistic.

I hope that I turn out to be foolishly alarmed about the way that this virus spreads. But to me, the exponential looks formidable.

Meanwhile, Tyler Cowen points to the British policy. As far as I can tell, they seem to be saying that you only need to worry about isolating known cases.

Some critics believe that the British approach will not slow the spread of the virus, and that the Brits know this. These critics see the Brits as consciously preferring to expose a large share of their population soon, on the theory that once they have immunity the crisis will be behind them.

The potential downside of that approach is that they might soon see their medical facilities overwhelmed, so that more cases become severe and fatal than otherwise might be the case. But if not, and their approach works, then they can certainly laugh at the rest of us.

Also, perhaps by the time you read this the Brits will have re-thought and retracted.

The case for forbearance

I believe that the best macroeconomic response to the virus crisis would be what I call forbearance. Bank regulators would tell banks that they will be allowed to fall below minimum capital requirements. They will be allowed to write down the value of loans without having to raise capital as a result. They will be encouraged to in turn offer forbearance to borrowers, provided that there is a reasonable prospect that borrowers will be able to get repayments back on track once the crisis has passed.

Under this policy, it will be up to banks to decide which borrowers are in short-term difficulty and which borrowers are never going to recover. If I were at a bank, I would bet on airlines coming back. I would not bet on cruise ships coming back.

You can think of forbearance as a selective soft bailout. When it comes to bailing out industries, you can think of a type I and type II error. Type I error is where you let a business collapse when it could survive with some help to tide it over. A type II error is where you save a business that is really not viable.

Ordinarily, you just let the market operate, and accept the errors that it makes. But the virus crisis threatens to become a financial crisis, and in a financial crisis there will be a lot of Type I errors. These in turn will cause economic activity to fall. But if you provide indiscriminate bailouts, you will make too many Type II errors.

If you provide funds to a troubled firm, then you may commit a Type II error without realizing it. If you only provide forbearance, then you discover your Type II error when even after the crisis passes the firm cannot get back on track. So that limits the duration of the error that you make.

If you just use generic macroeconomic instruments, such as fiscal and monetary stimulus, you end up with a lot of both types of errors. That is how I judge the response to the crisis of 2008. On top of that, there was all sorts of economically useless graft, such as the “green energy” programs included in the fiscal stimulus.

I am skeptical that either quantitative easing or the stimulus actually helped. That is because I think that the “aggregate demand” paradigm is flawed. Economic activity declined because particular patterns of specialization and trade were disrupted. This will also be the case with the virus crisis. More government spending or more expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet will just socialize more of the economy. That will be of little benefit in the short run, and it will cause harm in the long run.

My working assumption continues to be that the elites are two weeks behind in dealing with this crisis. That is, what President Trump did yesterday was probably what he should have done two weeks ago. What I would like to see the top leadership do is ask the Centers for Disease Control to come up with a plan for what to do if three weeks from now the number of cases continues to double every few days with no sign of stopping. Take that plan and execute it now.

The two-weeks-behind hypothesis

My working assumption is that American business and political elites are two weeks behind in their attempts to address the virus crisis. The steps they are taking now were necessary two weeks ago. And the steps that are needed now will not be taken for another two weeks.

So you can look at the news about events being canceled, telework being encouraged, and so on, and say that this is all for the good. But it would have been better to have taken these steps before, say, the Biogen conference.

So ask yourself, what are the steps that we will wish we had taken two weeks from now? Perhaps more self-quarantining by people who do not think they have been exposed.

Macroeconomics of the virus crisis, 4

Some very welcome humility from the economists on the IGM forum. They are asked whether we should think of this as mostly a demand shock or mostly a supply shock, and a lot of them refuse to take the bait.

Alesina says, “This is a new situation. We don’t have a clue.”

Duffie says, “For me, this is just too hard to entangle.”

Eichengreen says, “As someone who’s estimated lots of models designed to distinguish supply and demand shocks, good luck identifying them.”

Hall says, “I’m certain that the answer is totally uncertain.”

Schmalensee says, “Too early to call, I think. Workforce disruptions will affect demand as well as supply.”

There are others who are willing to try to pick one or the other. But some pick supply and some pick demand.

Of course, I think that the AS-AD paradigm is the wrong place to start. See my book.

Also, Tyler Cowen raises the possibility that the economy will suffer from a fragile financial system, which was fostered and joined by governments.

Macroeconomics of the virus crisis, 3

First, I think that this article from MIT Technology Review is essential reading, if you have not already seen it.

According to Duane Newton, the director of clinical microbiology at the University of Michigan, the biggest limitation in diagnostics is not the technology, but rather the regulatory approval process for new tests and platforms. While this process is critical for ensuring safety and efficacy, the necessary delays often “hamper the willingness and ability of manufacturers and laboratories to invest resources into developing and implementing new tests,” he says.

Case in point: FDA rules initially prevented state and commercial labs from developing their own coronavirus diagnostic tests, even if they could develop coronavirus PCR primers on their own. So when the only available test suddenly turned out to be bunk, no one could actually say what primer sets worked.

Read the whole article.

Next, today’s WSJ has many editorials and op-eds that discuss measures to help households get through the crisis. But the most interesting piece is by Hal Scott on the financial sector. He says that after the 2008 financial crisis abated

there was growing public concern about “moral hazard”—that government backstops and guarantees created incentives for risky behavior. In response, the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 limited the Fed’s lender-of-last-resort powers for nonbanks, an increasingly important part of the financial system. Fed loans to nonbanks can now be made only with the approval of the Treasury secretary. They must be done through a broad program, unlike the one-off rescue of AIG, and must meet heightened collateral requirements. Loans to nonbanks must be disclosed to congressional leaders within seven days and to the public within one year.

I agree that we should be concerned about the financial sector, because of the way that it can magnify an economic crisis. But just as in 2008, I would try to avoid loans to financial institutions and other forms of bailouts. Back, then, I proposed “forbearance,” meaning allowing banks to fall below regulatory capital standards for a while. I still prefer this approach. It might reduce the contraction of the financial sector without providing a direct transfer of resources from taxpayers to banks.

Commenter Jeff thought along similar lines.

I wonder if you couldn’t mitigate some of the worst effects of defaults with some kind of mass forbearance policy. After all, if Southwest no longer has the cash flow to cover the financing costs of it’s fleet, what are its creditors going to do in the middle of a public health crisis? Come and repo the jets? In order to do what with them?

Finally, the headline yesterday that stock had fallen 20 percent from their peak caused me to wonder whether that is too much. Here are the arguments for and against a sizable stock market drop.

The case for a sizable drop:

–When we have a recession, not only does GDP drop but the ratio of corporate profits to GDP also drops. This “double whammy” on profits is a reason that stocks should fall farther than the economy. Another way to think of this is to treat an index fund as a levered position in GDP. If GDP falls by X percent, then the index fund should fall by a multiple of X percent.

–A significant share of corporate profits of U.S. firms now depends on overseas activity. Some important trading partners appear likely to be hit particularly badly by both the virus and by their financial fragility.

The case against a sizable drop:

–Although trade and tourism are big industries, they are a relatively small share of the U.S. economy overall.

–This, too, shall pass. At some point, even trade and tourism will recover.