Redefining the Problem of Our Time

Piketty has written a book that nobody interested in a defining issue of our era can afford to ignore.

That is from John Cassidy. Other reviewers often speak of inequality as the defining issue of our time. Brad DeLong has collected many reviews. Clearly, this book is serving as a rallying point for the cause of redistributing rather than creating wealth. Its appeal to academics is particularly strong.

If you had asked me, I would have said that the defining issue of our time is unsustainable government finance. Most major national governments have made promises that they are unlikely to keep. Our state and local governments are cutting back on services, and in a few cases going bankrupt, in order to pay pensions to former employees. The outlook for politics is grim.

And yet we are being told to focus on inequality as the defining problem of our time.

I have not yet read the Piketty book. Perhaps I will find it persuasive. But I do not understand how Larry Summers, who believes that we are in a period of secular stagnation, with an excess of capital and an equilibrium real interest rate that is negative, can give a positive review of a book that says that we have such a capital scarcity that we will see a real interest rate greater than the economic growth rate for the indefinite future.

It seems to me that the development of India and China, along with ongoing technological change, is making the gap in incomes between those countries and ours smaller, while the gap within the United States widens. I am not convinced that this represents a net increase in inequality, much less that it is the defining problem of our time. Twenty years from now, my guess is that the people who are worried about this problem, and not the problem of unsustainable government finance, will not seem particularly astute.

Policy Proposals for Fishtown

Ron Haskins writes

The program of this type that has had the most success so far is called career academies, in which students organize into small learning communities to participate in academic and technical education for three or four years during high school. Perhaps the most important aspect of the program is the opportunity students have to gain several years of experience with local employers who provide career-specific learning experiences. An eight-year follow-up of young adults who had participated in career academies showed limited effects on young women but major effects on young men. Young men who had been in the program were about 33% more likely to be married, were about 30% more likely to live with their partners and their children, and earned about $30,000 more over the eight years than the men in the randomized control groups. Expanding the reach of career academies, especially in high-poverty areas, would be a wise investment.

He lists other ideas, including extending the Earned Income Tax Credit to single parents.

Denominator-Shifting

Atif Mian and Amir Sufi write,

what we want to focus on today is the remarkable separation in productivity and median real income since 1980. While the United States is producing twice as much per hour of work today compared to 1980, a small part of the gain in real income has gone to the bottom half of the income distribution. The gap between productivity and median real income is at an historic all-time high today.

Pointer from Mark Thoma.

They are comparing average output per hour to real median income per family. Rhetorically, they attribute the divergence in the two ratios to the numerators. That is, average output has grown faster than median income. However, there are also two denominators at work. The first denominator is “hours of work.” The second denominator is “family.” I suspect that a fair amount of the divergence in the two series is due to divergence in the denominators. That is, I suspect that the ratio of “hours of work” to the number of family units fell markedly between 1980 and today. There is a downward trend in hours worked, particularly for men. In addition, there is an upward trend in the number of family units, due to divorce and lower propensity to marry.

It would seem that this would be an easy issue to check.

The Financial Crisis and Wealth Transfer

Amir Sufi writes (with Atif Mian).

The strong house price rebound in high foreclosure-rate cities likely reflects these markets bouncing back after excessive price declines. But these foreclosed properties are not being bought by traditional owner-occupiers that plan on living in the home. Instead, they have been bought by investors in large numbers.

This is from a new blog spotted by Tyler Cowen, and both of the first two posts are worth reading in their entirety.

The picture that I get is of a pre-crisis economy in which middle- and lower-middle-income households thought they were doing well in the housing market. Then their house prices collapsed. Vulture investors swooped in to buy. Meanwhile, the government bailed out big banks and the stock market boomed. Some folks will credit the Fed for the latter. I don’t, but that is a bit beside the point here.

Net this all out–the sucker bets on housing by the non-rich, followed by big gains by wealthier folks in stocks and in foreclosed houses, and you get a picture of a huge regressive wealth transfer engineered in Washington. Carried out primarily by those who profess to be outraged by inequality.

Trifurcation?

Richard Reeves writes,

say, the top decile, or 10%, of the income distribution.

This stratum is not only prospering economically. For the people on this top rung, education levels are high and rising. Families are planned, marriages strong, neighborhoods safe and rich in social capital, networks plentiful, BMIs low and savings rates high.

Below these are what Reeves calls “the squeezed middle” and then the “entrenched poor. Reeves later writes,

Data recently unveiled by my colleague Gary Burtless, showing income growth since 1979 across the distribution, shows that in terms of after-tax income, those at the top have done really well since 1979; that’s perhaps not a surprise. What might be more instructive is the relative performance of the lowest quintile and the middle – ie. a 49% rise compared to a 36% rise. Income growth has clearly been weakest in the middle of the distribution.

Pointer from James Pethokoukis.

The New Piketty Book and Social Security Privatization

I have not read it, but Tyler is touting it. Apparently, Piketty argues that it is normal for the return on capital to exceed the growth rate of the economy.

I always thought that this was impossible. Ten years ago, I wrote,

If stock prices grow at 7 percent per year while the economy grows at 2 percent per year, then the ratio of stock prices to GDP (P/Y) fifty years from now will be more than ten times what it is today. How could that happen?

If the price-earnings ratio of the stock market (P/E) stays constant, then in order for P/Y to increase tenfold, the ratio of earnings to GDP (E/Y) has to increase tenfold. However, corporate profits are over 10 percent of national output today, so that if the ratio increases by tenfold, then corporate profits will be more than 100 percent of national output. That is impossible.

Alternatively, suppose that the ratio of corporate profits to national output stays constant. Then we need the P/E ratio to increase by tenfold in order to get a tenfold increase in P/Y. So, if the P/E ratio today is about 25, then in fifty years it will be 250. That would require investors to almost ignore risk and the time value of money in valuing stocks. No one believes that this is possible.

Perhaps Piketty has a better grasp on this than I do. But if the return on capital is going to exceed the growth rate of the economy, then this strikes me as powerful argument in favor of privatizing Social Security, so that people don’t get cheated out of these wonderful returns. Again, I have not read the book (it will be released in about 6 weeks). Does he come out in favor of privatizing Social Security? If not, then why not?

Mankiw on the Chetty Paper

He writes,

Chetty et al. finds that the regression of kids’ income rank on parents’ income rank has a coefficient of 0.3. (See Figure 1.) That implies an R2 for the regression of 0.09. In other words, 91 percent of the variance is unexplained by parents’ income.

I would be willing venture a guess, based on adoption studies, that a lot of that 9 percent is genetics rather than environment. That is, talented parents have talented kids partly because of good genes. Conservatively, let’s say half is genetics. That leaves only 4.5 percent of the variance attributed directly to parents’ income.

Read the whole post. In fact, if the correlation between kids’ income and parents’ income is only 0.3, then this is considerably lower than the heritability of many other traits.

The Raj Chetty Paper on Income Mobility

If you have only seen the blogosphere coverage and not read the paper, co-authored with Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, and Emmanuel Saez, then here are some findings you have missed.

the strongest predictors of upward mobility are measures of family structure such as the fraction of single parents in the area. As with race, parents’ marital status does not matter purely through its e ects at the individual level. Children of married parents also have higher rates of upward mobility if they live in communities with fewer single parents.

and

high upward mobility areas tend to have higher fractions of religious individuals and greater participation in local civic organizations.

and

no systematic correlation between mobility and local labor market conditions, rates of migration, or access to higher education.

The authors emphasize that these are correlations, not causal relationships. Still, these results seem more promising for social-conservative policy wonks than for progressive ones.

Larry Summers on Sectoral Productivity Disparities

He says,

people with higher wages now work more hours than people with lower wages. The time series tracks the cross section. Over time, as we have all gotten richer, the number of hours worked for many people has risen

and also

the simple fact is that the relative price of toys and a college education has changed by a factor of ten in a generation

Pointer from Timothy Taylor.

How do you connect these dots? One way is to scream “We need more government!” Because look at the inequality! Look at the low productivity in education and health care, and we know government ends up running the low-productivity sectors!

I had another way to connect the dots. You could say that the cost of living has gone way down for people who do not measure their self-worth by the prestige of the college to which their kids go and the breadth of their health insurance coverage. Many people can now afford what they think is a decent lifestyle without earning so much in the labor market. However, the anointed look at such people and say, “But you must attend an elite college. But you must have health insurance that covers all manner of medical services, not just major medical.”